WEBINAR #3: DIGITAL: WHAT REGULATORY MODEL FOR PLATFORMS?
←
→
Transcription du contenu de la page
Si votre navigateur ne rend pas la page correctement, lisez s'il vous plaît le contenu de la page ci-dessous
11th New Frontiers of Antitrust Conference WEBINAR #3: DIGITAL: WHAT REGULATORY MODEL FOR PLATFORMS? 5 November 2020 – 16:00 CET Nicolas Petit: Thank you very much, Edouard, and good afternoon to everyone here. We are very pleased to be here. Let me say a few words about the process that led to the organisation of this conference today and some words about the panellists before we move on to the discussion. So, when we prepared the conference last year in Paris, on the 19th of November with Professor Laurence Idot, Frédéric Jenny, Nicolas, the coronavirus crisis was very distant and almost inexistence. Hence, the working title we had was something like, what regulatory model for platforms? And our intuition was the European Commission and other agencies would still be making their minds by the time of the conference on whether to adopt regulation or reform the antitrust. And if regulation was the way to go, what kind of model should be followed? Something like customer protection, natural monopoly regulation, or supply retail type of regulation. And so, we expected the conference to contribute to the thinking on these issues. Now, fast forward to today, in the agency world, these questions seem to have reached a level of uncertainty. And at very fast speeds, agency who had been working on cases in the preceding years, appear quite certain to want a reformed antitrust or new regulation for digital industries. And many of these agencies are seeming to converge on a model of targeted regulation where there the symmetric regulation on platforms denominated as gatekeeper, systemic firms, or “too big to care” businesses. And there's a sense today that some form of new regulation is inevitable, and agencies mostly are toiling with operationalisation questions. What's left to discuss on a panel of this kind, today? This is the hard question for us. And, as I often like to say, if there's uncertainty in some areas in the community, it's open to question in general. Where there are any ideas mature enough to be taken for granted. So, there is indeed a discussion to have if I need to revalidate what we believe in. Also, many courts today are still yet to deal with the antitrust cases that were started by the agencies and their voice has not, for some of them, have been heard. Besides, the models of regulation and antitrust reform that are pushed forwards in various member states are not entirely similar. There is also competition in that space and these differences are instinct to investigate. And last but not least, agencies and regulators have not always expressed fairly clearly what they really want to achieve beyond the sort of formulaic statement that we want to promote competition in digital industries. Few days ago, Mark Scott, a journalist with Politico, wrote “if regulators and lawmakers really want to reinvent the business model for the internet, one not fuelled by personal information and an industry not dominated by a few global giants, someone Webinar #3 Digital: What regulatory model for platforms? Concurrences 11th New Frontiers of Antitrust - 5 November 2020 Verbatim transcript of oral presentations provided by Concurrences without prior vetting by the speakers. The views and opinions expressed in this Document do not necessarily represent those of the speakers’ institution or clients.
needs to spell out what this alternative might be”. Saying that market failures exist is the first step. But devising and promoting an alternative model is another one. And we're still in uncertainty here. So, to help us discuss these issues and gain clarity on the means and purposes of this exercise, we are joined today by Isabelle de Silva, first, who is “Présidente de l’Autorité de la concurrence” in Paris. Andreas Mundt, Chairman of the Bundeskartellamt. Simeon Thornton, Director at the UK CMA, Séverine Schramek, Partner with Cleary Gottlieb, Paris. And Antoine Chapsal Managing Principal at Analysis Group. Their full biography is available in Concurrences website. And in the interest of starting the discussion and kicking off, I will direct you to their curriculums that are available online. Now, what is going to happen is the following, we'll have a discussion for about an hour, and we will move along with four main questions. And then that will be 25 minutes also for the Q&A with the audience. So, the four questions will be dealt with as we go. And so, to start, the first question that we decided we would ask the panellists, is the following. The question is, if existing antitrust is insufficient, do we really need to replace it with regulation? And why don't we just start by improving existing antitrust tools? Isabelle will go first followed by Andreas, Antoine and Simeon. Isabelle, always an honour to be with you on a panel. You have the floor. Isabelle de Silva: Merci Nicolas, merci à tous, je suis ravie d’avoir cette occasion de partager avec vous mes réflexions et bravo à la revue Concurrences de maintenir l’usage du français pour cette conférence, qui traditionnellement se réunit à Paris. La question que vient de poser Nicolas me parait très bonne : y-a-t-il en réalité un choix entre d’une part rénover des outils du droit de la concurrence et d’autre part considérer la nécessité d’une réglementation des plateformes. Je crois vraiment qu’aujourd’hui les deux chantiers sont engagés en parallèle. Je crois que l’amélioration des outils du droit de la concurrence fait l’objet d’un constat partagé par tous, à l’heure où on se demande quels nouveaux outils règlementaires pourraient être adoptés, notamment par la Commission européenne, mais aussi dans plusieurs pays de l’Union européenne et au-delà. Il est intéressant de se rappeler quelle est la part spécifique du droit de la concurrence, qu’est ce qui fait son avantage et quels sont peut-être ces inconvénients, ou les points sur lesquels il peut être amélioré. Cela me parait utile de rappeler en quoi le droit de la concurrence est bien adapté, de façon générale, mais aussi pour traiter les enjeux numériques. D’abord, un premier point est que le droit de la concurrence s’applique en fonction d’un marché, et donc il n’y a pas tout le débat que nous avons dans d’autres domaines de réglementation des plateformes sur le pays d’origine, puisque là où un acteur de type plateforme est actif sur un marché, le droit de la concurrence pourra intervenir. Un deuxième atout très fort du droit de la concurrence tel qu’il est pratiqué en France et en Europe, est qu’il ne connait pas de barrières sectorielles. Il est d’application extrêmement large. En France, la seule limite serait peut-être l’exercice des prérogatives de puissance publique par Webinar #3 Digital: What regulatory model for platforms? Concurrences 11th New Frontiers of Antitrust - 5 November 2020 Verbatim transcript of oral presentations provided by Concurrences without prior vetting by the speakers. The views and opinions expressed in this Document do not necessarily represent those of the speakers’ institution or clients.
l’Etat ou par des organismes publics, mais sinon, quel que soit le secteur il peut intervenir. Or, on voit bien que l’une des difficultés de l’économie numérique c’est qu’elle remet en cause beaucoup de barrières sectorielles. Donc c’est un atout qu’il faut conserver. Enfin, troisième avantage, nous avons aujourd’hui une boîte à outils très vaste, avec des remèdes comportementaux, des procédures d’engagement, des procédures de sanction, des remèdes qui peuvent être structurels et aussi un atout capital l’intervention rapide par les mesures conservatoires. Le dernier avantage qui me parait nécessaire à mettre en avant est ce réseau intégré qui fonctionne en Europe, avec cette articulation entre le niveau national et le niveau européen. Je crois pour autant que la rénovation du droit de la concurrence est indispensable et elle est déjà largement engagée. Quelques exemples, tout d’abord, l’adoption de la directive ECN+, qui date de l’année dernière avec du point de vue français un atout qui nous sera donné très vite, qui sera la possibilité de s’autosaisir, en mesures conservatoires, ce qui n’était pas possible jusqu’à présent et ce qui est extrêmement utile, notamment pour répondre à des problématiques de plateformes et, par ailleurs, la possibilité qui sera désormais clarifiée d’adresser des injonctions structurelles, en cas d’infraction au droit de la concurrence. Donc il s’agit d’un outil relativement récent, puisque nous sommes en train de discuter au Parlement français de la transposition de cette directive, qui va devenir une réalité concrète dans les toutes prochaines semaines. D’autres chantiers ont été engagés et doivent être poursuivis. Tout d’abord un usage plus large des mesures conservatoires, c’était déjà le cas assez largement en France mais la Commission européenne, par exemple, a emboité le pas et a montré par une action très volontaire à cet égard qu’elle entendait maintenant utiliser beaucoup plus que par le passé cet outil, que sont les mesures conservatoires. Finalement, face à ce tableau, il y a encore des progrès à faire, je crois d’abord que la durée des procédures reste un point sur lequel toutes les autorités doivent progresser, que ce soit au niveau national ou en Europe, cela a été dit mille fois, des procédures qui durent des années, c’est évidemment trop long. Il faut aller à un rythme beaucoup resserré. Cela concerne aussi les tribunaux, qui doivent également faire en sorte que les décisions sur les recours interviennent plus rapidement. On connait, par exemple, ces trois cas très importants de la Commission, Google Shopping, Google Android et Google AdSense, pour lesquels nous n’avons pas encore la réponse. Finalement, est-ce qu’une régulation est nécessaire ? Beaucoup d’intervenants dans le débat considèrent qu’aujourd’hui c’est mettre la charrue avant les bœufs ou adresser une mauvaise réponse que de considérer des réglementations comme celles qui sont débattues en Europe, plutôt que de conserver le droit de la concurrence, tel que nous le connaissons. Dans ma vision des choses, je crois vraiment qu’il faut chercher une complémentarité, la réglementation ex- ante, par exemple, n’est pas une alternative ou une critique en soi du droit de la concurrence tel qu’il existe, ce qu’il faut rechercher c’est l’effectivité. Et on voit bien avec le débat sur le Digital Services Act ou Digital Markets Act que ce que l’on recherche, ce sont finalement des choses complémentaires à ce qu’on peut faire par les outils du droit de la concurrence. Webinar #3 Digital: What regulatory model for platforms? Concurrences 11th New Frontiers of Antitrust - 5 November 2020 Verbatim transcript of oral presentations provided by Concurrences without prior vetting by the speakers. The views and opinions expressed in this Document do not necessarily represent those of the speakers’ institution or clients.
Pour donner une illustration d’une application horizontale beaucoup plus rapide de règles dont on aurait estimé qu’elles sont pertinentes, parmi les thèmes qui sont en débat dans le DSA, il y a, par exemple, l’interdiction du self-preferencing ou l’accès à certaines données. Si l’on considère, peut-être à partir d’un cas contentieux, que ces obligations sont nécessaires, l’idée du DSA ou du DMA pourrait être finalement de répandre beaucoup plus vite ces règles à d’autres entreprises que celle qui fait l’objet d’une procédure pour infraction au droit de la concurrence. Pour conclure à ce stade sur la question qui était posée, je pense qu’aujourd’hui on a des réponses qui sont en train d’être apportées sur les carences du droit de la concurrence. À mon avis, l’un des domaines d’attention qu’il faut vraiment conserver est le contrôle des concentrations. Il n’y a pas que l’antitrust qui nécessite une remise à niveau, et finalement une revitalisation, je crois qu’en matière de contrôle des concentrations il faut aller plus loin sur l’analyse concurrentielle des acquisitions faites par des plateformes, par exemple pour aller au- delà de ces délimitations de marché qui conduisent peut-être parfois à des visions trop restrictives des risques pour la concurrence, qui sont liés à des acquisitions. Je me référais à l’acquisition Facebook/WhatsApp à cet égard. Un autre domaine qui pose problème est le vide des opérations d’acquisition qui ne sont soumises à aucun contrôle. A cet égard, nous venons d’avoir une avancée très significative, avec l’annonce par la Commission européenne de reconsidérer de façon beaucoup plus ouverte que par le passé des renvois qui pourraient être faits par l’article 22 du Règlement 2004, sur demande d’autorité nationale. Pour autant, il y a aussi des choses qui doivent être faites à droit constant, il ne faut pas l’oublier. C’est le réexamen des notions traditionnelles comme la position dominante. Il y a un vrai travail de réflexion à faire sur ce qu’est le critère d’une position dominante. Nous avons fait des propositions à ce sujet dans notre document de Policy Paper sur concurrence et numérique, par exemple en considérant qu’il faudrait prendre en compte beaucoup plus aujourd’hui non pas simplement une part de marché sur un marché déterminé mais la possibilité de mobiliser une communauté d’utilisateurs sur différents marchés, qui peuvent être liés. Un autre exemple de travail très concret et important, qui va nous occuper encore sur 2021, c’est la révision de la notice sur les marchés pertinents. C’est un travail qui a été bien engagé à présent entre la Commission européenne et les autorités nationales et qui va nous permettre de prendre en compte des évolutions nécessaires comme la prise en compte de la concurrence potentielle des acteurs plateformes, par exemple. Pour conclure, le travail de modernisation et de mise à jour du droit de la concurrence est très largement engagé. Je crois qu’avec tous les chantiers que j’ai indiqués, nous avons quasiment tout ce que nous pourrions souhaiter, même si nous aurions souhaité aller encore plus loin sur le contrôle des concentrations, en soumettant certaines plateformes à des obligations d’information sur toutes leurs opérations d’acquisition. Nous verrons si une fois que le DSA/DMA aura été un peu stabilisé au niveau européen, il sera possible de le compléter sur ce point ou de prendre des initiatives législatives nationales. Par Webinar #3 Digital: What regulatory model for platforms? Concurrences 11th New Frontiers of Antitrust - 5 November 2020 Verbatim transcript of oral presentations provided by Concurrences without prior vetting by the speakers. The views and opinions expressed in this Document do not necessarily represent those of the speakers’ institution or clients.
ailleurs, je crois que sur le plan de la jurisprudence, et finalement de la pratique décisionnelle, on est aussi dans une phase de vitalité des décisions prises par les autorités nationales de concurrence : la décision Facebook du Bundeskartellamt est un exemple de décision qui montre comment les autorités peuvent prendre en compte de façon large les pratiques des plateformes pour remédier à toutes les mises en danger possibles du droit de la concurrence d’un nouveau type. Nicolas Petit: Merci beaucoup Isabelle. Handing over immediately to Andreas. Andreas Mundt: Thank you very much, Nicolas. It is always an honour and a pleasure to be at one of Nicolas' conferences. I am very happy to be here today. I would very much have preferred to be in Paris right now, but this is an excellent substitute. I think the question how this should go forward/what road to take is the subject of intense debate worldwide. Do we continue with competition law enforcement or do we opt for regulation? I think there is agreement around the globe to a certain extent that there is need for more and stricter enforcement. So far, we have tried to get by with competition enforcement and I think we have really made good use of the tools that we have at hand. We have imposed behavioural remedies and we have tried to work with structural remedies where possible. But there is one thing that we have to take into account. Policymakers at any rate think that we need to take further steps and that we need to do more. And now everything is being debated. The first step is to strengthen the existing tools of competition law. The second one is to regulate certain types of companies or businesses, in particular ‘ecosystems’. And some areas of the world even call for a third step, that is breaking up the tech giants in order to restore competition in certain digital sectors. The joint paper recently published by France and the Netherlands clearly states that we should not leave a possible break up of companies aside. You could also look at the US and the youngest lawsuit that is brought against Google by the Department of Justice and state prosecutors. According to the media, there are considerations whether to force Google to sell at least parts of the company, for example Google’s Chrome browser. Of course, breaking up a company is always the very last resort. Less severe alternatives should always be tried first, especially since, compared to the EU, we have so far seen little enforcement activity in the US with regard to digital markets. In Europe, we take a very evolutionary approach and I think that is a good thing. Competition law has been enforced in a rather strict manner, just think of many major cases in France, Paris, Brussels and also here in Bonn brought against the big tech companies Amazon, Google and Facebook. Isabelle has already mentioned the Facebook decision by the Bundeskartellamt, where we imposed behavioural remedies prohibiting Facebook from combining user data from different sources. Personally, I always describe that as an « internal divestiture » or rather unbundling of Facebook’s data. This case is a good example that in some complex abuse cases it might be sufficient to unbundle individual parts, services or processes within a company. Webinar #3 Digital: What regulatory model for platforms? Concurrences 11th New Frontiers of Antitrust - 5 November 2020 Verbatim transcript of oral presentations provided by Concurrences without prior vetting by the speakers. The views and opinions expressed in this Document do not necessarily represent those of the speakers’ institution or clients.
Policymakers, however, are of the opinion that we need more and stricter enforcement measures, which also have to be implemented more rapidly. It is true that proceedings are not as fast as they should be since the need for speed on the one hand is opposed by the need for a thorough legal and economic assessment of the matter in question on the other hand, also with regard to possible court proceedings. So, it is not surprising that this demand for more and stricter enforcement has been taken up by legislators in Europe. The European Commission is working on two legislative proposals: The Digital Services Act, which will update the e-Commerce Directive, and the Digital Markets Act. The DMA will include two main pillars: The first one is a certain type of ex-ante regulation, a list of dos and don'ts for big digital gatekeepers. And secondly, there will be a market investigation framework, formerly known as the ‘new competition tool’. All this is still quite abstract and many parameters are still vague. But from what we know so far, the DMA outlines promising regulatory approaches. And I am quite confident that the Commission is determined to avoid overregulation with chilling effects on competition. When we turn to a national level, we can see that the same is happening with regard to the member states. EU Commissioner Thierry Breton has just said that member states are very close in their approach regarding gatekeeper tools. And I have a strong feeling that there is a lot of consensus among member states and among competition agencies of the member states. As can be seen here in Germany, where the 10th Amendment to the German Competition Actis currently going through the legislative process, This proposal bridges the divide between competition law and more traditional regulation. I always refer to that as « competition law plus » with « regulation » coherently integrated into the existing toolkit. We are going to introduce a new provision, Section 19a, which to a certain extent may be even revolutionary. This provision will focus on undertakings of paramount significance for competition across markets. We will assess not only competition or dominance on one market but also the interplay between and integration across markets. The provision is going to focus on ‘ecosystems’. There will be a clear list of conduct that the Bundeskartellamt can prohibit based on theories of harm manifested in the law. If we deem a company to be of paramount significance we can prohibit certain behaviour in the future even on markets where this company is not yet dominant. One example are envelopment strategies. However, there will be the possibility of objective justification on a case by case basis with a reversed burden of proof. In my view, our approach really develops traditional competition law in an innovative way to adjust it to the digital economy. I also hope that we will make our proceedings faster than they have been in the past, because we will have many clarifications in the law. We have manifested theories of harm in the law, and we have clearly designated the companies to which this new provision is going to apply. I think this is very important. This is an approach that really complements our traditional toolbox with regard to the abuse of dominance in digital markets. Webinar #3 Digital: What regulatory model for platforms? Concurrences 11th New Frontiers of Antitrust - 5 November 2020 Verbatim transcript of oral presentations provided by Concurrences without prior vetting by the speakers. The views and opinions expressed in this Document do not necessarily represent those of the speakers’ institution or clients.
So, it is not so much a question of what we need and more a question of whether to reshape traditional competition law or establish a regulatory approach. I think you can implement the necessary steps to better regulate these companies under competition law by developing it further with regard to digital markets, taking into account all the new phenomena which did not exist when most of our competition laws were drafted and passed the legislative process. In Germany, back in 1958, nobody spoke of network effects or data-driven business models, and this is going to be adapted further now. Thank you. Nicolas Petit: Thank you very much, Andreas. You and Isabel are almost within the 9’30, 10 minutes talk. There might be some tested collision around your score on timing. Now, probably it's the right time to move on to Antoine Chapsal. You have some slides if I'm not mistaken? Antoine Chapsal: Yes, indeed. So, thank you, Nicolas. This is a great pleasure to be here and to have the opportunity to sponsor this conference with Cleary. So well, I have to say that I do agree with what I heard so far, and what I am going to give you is some economic perspective on what we said. So, the first question we should ask, next slide, please, is what is a platform? So, I think everybody knows what it is now. It's a firm that creates value connecting two or more groups of users, with each group affecting the other's utility. Okay. And this interaction between the various sides of the platform is characterised by what we call indirect network effect, and this was what has been just mentioned. So, what we need to know is that there are many different kinds of platforms and there is a large variety of business models. So next slide please. So, what's interesting is that commentators have raised a number of potential antitrust issue that may arise from platforms. So, one is platforms are prone to tipping. So indeed, some people argue that we are in a situation where the winners take it all, so there may be competition for the market, which by the way, it's important. But once the winner is in, the market is no longer contestable. We also might face new kinds of practices, such as self- preferencing, platform envelopment, which is a form of bundling between platforms. One also very important argument is one that has been just mentioned, is the idea that speed is of the essence. Okay, so of course successful platforms can grow very quickly, and antitrust processes may be too slow to efficiently address anti-competitive behaviour. So, the key question is do these potential challenges provide justification for ex-ante regulation of platform? Next slide, please. So of course, I think we need to adapt our antitrust framework, and I do believe also that ex-ante regulation can be, in some instances, a solution. So, what we need to keep in mind, however, is that the development of platform has been extremely beneficial to consumers, and they are beneficial to consumers because they address changing needs, they introduce new technology and products, and they reduce certain production cost. Anyway, we could regulate this market if they have some structural fixture that prevent them from being efficient, and to be more specific, from a pure economic perspective, competition policy is appropriate when competition can result in efficient resource allocation. So, we need Webinar #3 Digital: What regulatory model for platforms? Concurrences 11th New Frontiers of Antitrust - 5 November 2020 Verbatim transcript of oral presentations provided by Concurrences without prior vetting by the speakers. The views and opinions expressed in this Document do not necessarily represent those of the speakers’ institution or clients.
to make sure that competition is not mitigated by firm behaviour and competition agencies should have the resources to quickly punish such behaviour. And if speed is of the essence, which is something that I do believe, impose interim measures, and Isabelle de Silva just mentioned this, power and opportunity. On the other end, regulation is very useful and adequate when competition yields inefficient resource allocation, and when we have significant market failure. Next slide, please. So, the question is what should we do? And here, I cannot agree more with what Isabelle de Silva has presented. I think we need to adapt our competition policy framework. We need to analyse the sources of competition pressure. So far, we are doing this using the definition of relevant markets, the concept of dominance, but we need to face the fact that these tools are binary, either you are belonging to the relevant market or you don't, they are static, and they are not well adapted to platforms. Okay, they do not fully capture the source of competitive pressure and, for instance, the fact that the competitive position of one platform can change very quickly. So, another thing that we need probably to specify, specific theory of harm, but as Isabelle de Silva just said, Article 102 is flexible enough to take into account these different kinds of practices that platforms may implement. One very important point also mentioned by Isabelle de Silva is killer acquisition, so I think that this is a very important issue, and this is something that is discussed in France, and this is something that has already been addressed by some competition agencies. So, the question we should ask then is are these change enough? This is a question we have to tackle now. So next slide please. So, well the first thing that, if we want ex-ante regulation, as could be the case, we are going to face some challenges. One is that we should regulate if we have a clear view of the market failure we want correct and the role played by platform generating them. So, one example I have here is, of course, market power, but we can also discuss, for instance, information asymmetry, which is another big market failure, and my interpretation of the reason why we should, for instance, regulate the use of personal data, why privacy is a good example, is that mostly because there is a significant information asymmetry between the individual who offer their data and the platform that requests data. So, this is what we call a salience issue. And there is a huge discrepancy between the individual short-term, tangible benefit from providing the platform with data and potential long-term harm. So here, the idea is that we have a clear marker failure, and so regulation makes sense. Next slide. So maybe now I can tackle the second challenge I see in ex-ante regulation, which is the practical consideration that is raised by the DSA and NCT. So, the first question we can ask is when doing prohibition of some practices makes sense for a policy design perspective? And well, here we know that blanket prohibition makes sense where there is a clear harm arising from a well-defined practice, otherwise it can be welfare reducing. One question is what kind of practice should we blacklist? Okay, and there are some efficiencies should they be blacklisted. One area that is often discussed is banning expansion of a platform in an adjustment market. And while this is also an interesting tool, I think this is something that should be, of course, considered carefully, but on the other end, a big platform can challenge another big platform entering an adjacent market. And yesterday, Apple announced that it is getting into search, and I think that makes not much economic sense from preventing Apple from doing so. Webinar #3 Digital: What regulatory model for platforms? Concurrences 11th New Frontiers of Antitrust - 5 November 2020 Verbatim transcript of oral presentations provided by Concurrences without prior vetting by the speakers. The views and opinions expressed in this Document do not necessarily represent those of the speakers’ institution or clients.
So, we need to understand that this kind of ex-ante regulation are tools that can structure very easily markets. So, then we have the trade-off between clarity and certainty on the one end before a more flexible approach. So here are clearly the basic trade-off economists have in mind when they have to compare different regulation models. So of course, we have prescriptive rules that may miss certain angles and capture conduct that is not harmful, but we have also high-level principle on the other end that could easily be too lax, or too tight, or inappropriate. One question also is do we want a rigid and symmetric regulatory tool? The question, as I already mentioned, is that platforms are very different, so maybe we will need something that is flexible. There are some issues about innovation and incentives to invest. And so far, the main platforms are investing in research very, very significant amount of money. I think GAFAM’s investment in 2018 was around €70 billion euros, so it's a significant amount of money. So, the question is how actually regulation may affect such incentive to invest. One question is also what kind of welfare we are trying to look after. And what I understand is that we are putting greater emphasis on supplier and competitors than on user and consumers. So, this is something that we need also to have in mind. And my last question is what is a gatekeeper? I don't care about the word itself; I care about what it really means and whether there is some definition that can be used for all kinds of platforms. So again, I'm not saying that we should not regulate, I think regulation can be a very efficient tool. I think, as Isabelle de Silva mentioned, that it can be complementary to some adapted policy framework, so I really do believe this. The question is that my position is that we have still some work to do before launching such a regulatory framework. Thank you so much. Nicolas Petit: Thank you, Antoine. And handing over immediately to Simeon. We are already quite late on the timing, so Simeon has his fair share, but in the next rounds, we'll have to be shorter. Simeon go ahead. Simeon Thornton: Thank you, Nicolas. I'll do my best to be brief. At CMA, we recently published a market study into online platforms and digital advertising, and that had a specific focus on Google and Facebook. And that study did indeed, to answer your question, advocate a new pro-competition regulatory regime for online platforms. It's based around the idea of an enforceable code of conduct for platforms that have significant market power, and also what we called a set of pro- competition interventions, which are really designed to tackle the sources of market power, such as data related interventions, means of increasing interoperability, etc. Why did we reach that conclusion? And why did we think that solely relying on existing antitrust powers was not sufficient? Well in the study, we found that both Google and Facebook were largely insulated from competition by a number of barriers to entry and expansion, and those include factors such as Webinar #3 Digital: What regulatory model for platforms? Concurrences 11th New Frontiers of Antitrust - 5 November 2020 Verbatim transcript of oral presentations provided by Concurrences without prior vetting by the speakers. The views and opinions expressed in this Document do not necessarily represent those of the speakers’ institution or clients.
economies of scale, network effects, the power of defaults on consumer behaviour, unequal access to user data, which is a really important input into serving targeted digital advertising, a lack of transparency and asymmetric information, which restricts the ability of the demand side to impose a sufficient disciplining influence on the behaviour of the platforms, and, of course, the increasing importance of ecosystems, which yes, we certainly recognise have benefits for consumers, but also afford the big platforms the opportunity to leverage market power from a core market to an adjacent market. And in short, these factors have to both Google and Facebook having entrenched market power. If you look at the data Google's had over 90% of UK searches and search advertising revenue over the last 10 years. We were able to do a bit of analysis, comparing the prices of Google and Bing, and we found that Google's prices were about 30 to 40% higher than Bing's on a like-for-like basis. When you look at Facebook, a similar position. It's had over 50% of display advertising revenues, and its average revenue per user has gone up astronomically over the last nine years or so by a factor of about 10. So given this context, I think there are probably four key reasons why we reached our headline conclusion that a new regulatory regime is required, and this does pick up some of the points made by previous speakers. The first of those is that those barriers to entry and expansion that I highlighted; they are self-reinforcing. And what that means is that if you are to tackle competition concerns in these sectors, you need to act on several fronts simultaneously in parallel, and that requires a regulatory regime rather than the single-issue focus of a typical antitrust case. So that's the first point. Secondly, again a point that's been made already, the markets are fast-moving and the technology underpinning them moves very quickly. And what that means is that where you do have some form of regulatory intervention in place, you need to have the power to monitor it, to revisit it, to assess that it remains fit for purpose, and, if necessary, to change it. And again, you need a regulatory regime in place to do that rather than our existing tools. The third point is that I think we all recognise on the panel that competition in these markets can be undermined very quickly. That's particularly the case where APIs can be shut off literally overnight, turning off someone's business model. Given that, you need a tool that can act very rapidly, and we all know that the big celebrated antitrust cases that have been brought at a European level have taken many years to prosecute. And that is too slow, given the propensity for harm to happen very rapidly. And then the final point I wanted to make is that the markets themselves, I can say this having looked into the details of digital advertising, they are pretty complex. And I think there is a merit in having a body that builds up regulatory expertise over time, so it can be a source of expertise. And that's another reason for an ex-ante regulatory regime. So, in short, we don't think what is required is an incremental tweak to our existing powers. We do think we need a fundamental reform of sorts, but just to pick up a point that Andreas made, we do agree that this is a complement to our existing panels. It's not a substitute for them. There are still cases in which you'd want to bring a traditional antitrust case where the behaviour is particularly egregious or what you think there's strong merit in the deterrence effect of a big fine, but we do think this is a necessary complement to our existing panels. Webinar #3 Digital: What regulatory model for platforms? Concurrences 11th New Frontiers of Antitrust - 5 November 2020 Verbatim transcript of oral presentations provided by Concurrences without prior vetting by the speakers. The views and opinions expressed in this Document do not necessarily represent those of the speakers’ institution or clients.
Nicolas Petit: Thank you, that's very helpful to get a sense of your experience at the CMA with these investigations too. Now, I want to move us directly to the next question, since we're a bit over time, and the next question is way more pointed. And it could be a yes or no question actually, so think about a yes or no answer, and maybe a short justification. The question is about the NCT, which is very close to the concept of the NCA, but it means something different. The question is should the new competition tool, so this emulation of the market inquiry regime in the United Kingdom that the European Commission would like to adopt, which would entitle the Commission to go after certain types of market failures which fall short of the thresholds found in Article 101 and Article 102, should the NCT be targeted at digital markets or should it be broader? And we had a survey on that. So, I'd like to pick up your views. We'll start with Séverine. Séverine Schrameck: Yes, thank you very much, Nicolas. So, the survey, interestingly, gives as a result 55% of no and 45% between yes and I don't know, if I picked that correctly. And so, my personal position to what you were saying to give a yes or no, is no. So, it looks like I'm targeting 45% of the audience right now, and I don't know if we're going to do another survey at the end of this, would be no or not. Maybe it's better if we don't, but maybe we give you a bit of background if I can have my first slide on. Yes, well the second one, actually. The next slide, yes. So, the New Competition Tool, as it was presented in the consultation of the European Commission, was split into four potential options, and these options were crossing two criteria. The first criteria were should the scope of the tool be based on dominance or not? And again, I'll leave this one aside because your question is really about a scenario where there is no dominance-based test, but a scenario where there is a market structure-based test. And if we are there, the question is do we want to have a horizontal scope covering all markets or more limited scope? And the way the NCT was conceived at the very beginning was it was presented, and the Commission consultation was two-fold, either we had a tool applicable to every single sector or we had the tool that would be sector limited but we'd still have a pretty broad scope targeting two types of markets, either markets which would have characteristic pointing to risk for competition or to a structural lack of competition. And I think they were more or less the same reasoning between these two concepts. One was maybe more preventive, structural risk, the other more intervening after the risk has materialised, a structural lack competition. But it was to address markets with certain characteristics which made fear some kind of market deficiency. And so now there seems that there is a trend or rumours about the fact that the New Competition Tool would not even be targeted to market with specific characteristics but to the digital sector. And well, I think it makes sense to understand why you don't want to have a very, very broad scope targeting each and every single market, carrying out a market investigation has a cost. There is some economic reason why competition authorities want to have some priority in terms of sectors that they want to address, and that they would address the sectors in which they are Webinar #3 Digital: What regulatory model for platforms? Concurrences 11th New Frontiers of Antitrust - 5 November 2020 Verbatim transcript of oral presentations provided by Concurrences without prior vetting by the speakers. The views and opinions expressed in this Document do not necessarily represent those of the speakers’ institution or clients.
at a higher risk. So, you would see some reason to claim for what on the slide is a feature that is option four, and what was featured as option four by the Commission. Now, if we now restrict that to even narrower scope, which will be just digital, I think this is another story, and this is a major departure from the initial proposal, and maybe from the essence of what competition law has been historically. And I think President de Silva said very well at the very beginning, within the first minute of this webinar, that one of the characteristics of competition law is that there is no sectorial barrier. Competition rule by essence is supposed to be neutral, and that's what makes the difference between regulation and competition. And so yes, we are looking at tools that would bridge the division between competition and regulation, and it would be somewhere in the middle. I think President Mundt said that before as well, and I think that's very right, but I think if we are limiting the scope of this New Competition Tool to digital, then I'm not sure we're really keeping the link to competition, and I think we are really shifting to the regulation of the scope. And this has other consequences, and maybe we can move to my next slide. When we were looking at the characteristic of the two types of market that were targeted by this option four, they were market which presented some risk or some lack of competition because they had some specific features that were characterised by network and scale effects, lack of multi- homing, lock-in effect, barrier to entry, lock-in effect again for lack of competition, data accumulation. And I think these characteristics are not typical or are not something that distinguishes the digital world from other industries. I think these are all things that you can find in other sectors, be it telecom, be it electricity, and it's interesting to see that the marketing investigation capacity that the CMA has is actually targeting that kind of market and not focused on the digital sectors only. So that's my first reflection. My second thought about that is that there is a lot of heterogenic in the digital world. So, we would apply this tool to a world that includes some products or services, however, you want to call it, that have more connection to the real economy than to some other platforms. So, if you think about, let's say the website, La Fourchette, which would be in the digital world, I think it has more to do with [inaudible] than WhatsApp, for example. And so, it's a bit difficult to see why this digital as such, is a relevant criterion for the application of the tool or not. Maybe just to conclude, if I have 30 seconds left. I think what is really, really important is that we're looking at the tool that is disruptive from any other tool that competition authorities had so far. And I agree with a lot of what has been said earlier in particular by a professional. And I think what is very important is that this tool is applied in a differentiated manner on a case- by-case basis. Either if it is applicable in digital, because as I've said, there is a lot of heterogeneity in the digital world, or if it's applicated in a broader scope. Nicolas Petit: Okay. Thank you, Séverine. That was very helpful to kick us off on this question. So, I'm turning now to Isabelle with a very straightforward question, should the NCT be exclusively targeted towards digital markets, yes or no? Webinar #3 Digital: What regulatory model for platforms? Concurrences 11th New Frontiers of Antitrust - 5 November 2020 Verbatim transcript of oral presentations provided by Concurrences without prior vetting by the speakers. The views and opinions expressed in this Document do not necessarily represent those of the speakers’ institution or clients.
Isabelle de Silva : Merci Nicolas. Je pense que le champ du NCT devrait ou aurait vocation à être général et à couvrir tous les secteurs de l’économie, sans distinction. Je crois cela parce que, comme Séverine l’a très bien expliqué, le NCT peut s’avérer extrêmement utile pour tous les secteurs de l’économie et la meilleure façon de le démontrer c’est de considérer que la CMA, qui a un pouvoir similaire depuis plusieurs années, l’a essentiellement appliqué dans des secteurs de l’économie traditionnels. A quel type de problèmes cela peut répondre ? Par exemple des problèmes qui ont été constitués par des acquisitions par un opérateur dominant - on retrouve la problématique du contrôle de concentration sous les seuils - ou encore des problèmes liés à des structures de marché oligopolistiques, où l’on a un marché qui ne fonctionne pas bien, sans pour autant avoir un abus. Il y a toute une variété de situations dans lesquelles le droit de la concurrence tel qu’il est, avec ses outils répressifs, n’a pas véritablement de réponse. Un autre avantage du NCT avec un champ d’application large est qu’il peut déboucher sur toute une série d’issues, pas seulement des séparations structurelles très massives et considérables comme on peut les imaginer, mais parfois sur des remèdes de type règlementaire, peut-être juste des remèdes qui interviennent sur un mode de commercialisation ou une transparence du marché sur telle ou telle catégorie d’informations. Pour autant, on a pu le voir dans les dernières annonces qui ont été faites, mais qui devront encore être confirmées début décembre, que le champ large du NCT n’était pas forcément à l’ordre du jour. Cela peut être lié à un sujet un peu technique qui est que dans la proposition initiale de la Commission, il y avait, d’un côté, un DSA avec des règles générales et des applications spécifiques et, de l’autre côté, un NCT avec des applications faisant suite à une étude de marché. On voit bien que dans la nouvelle proposition de la Commission, elle a un peu rationnalisé tout cela avec ce qui sera maintenant le Digital Markets Act, qui pourrait avoir deux branches : des règles générales d’interdiction ou d’obligation et un outil plus ciblé. Bien sûr, si on commence avec un outil qui est ciblé sur le numérique, il y a un inconvénient majeur que j’avais pointé précédemment, le fait que l’on risque d’avoir des débats sur ce qui est numérique. Je ne crois pas que le numérique soit un secteur, je crois qu’il peut affecter tous les secteurs de l’économie. On aura un problème un peu juridique, qui sera que des entreprises pourront invoquer cette limite sectorielle pour dire « on n’est pas dans le champ et vous ne pouvez pas intervenir. » Cela peut peut-être se résoudre avec une rédaction suffisamment large et même, à supposer que l’on commence qu’avec le secteur numérique, pour autant, ce n’est pas une raison de ne pas le faire, parce que cela pourra ultérieurement être élargi, si on a l’impression que cet outil est utile. Je dirais qu’aujourd’hui nous avons les avancées qui seront faites pas la Commission début décembre et nous verrons ce qui sera retenu à ce stade. Si l’on voit bien tout l’intérêt qu’il y a à avoir un champ d’application large, pour autant, avec un champ d’application restreint au numérique, l’on pourrait quand même avoir une valeur ajoutée à ce type d’outil. Webinar #3 Digital: What regulatory model for platforms? Concurrences 11th New Frontiers of Antitrust - 5 November 2020 Verbatim transcript of oral presentations provided by Concurrences without prior vetting by the speakers. The views and opinions expressed in this Document do not necessarily represent those of the speakers’ institution or clients.
Nicolas Petit: Merci Isabelle pour votre réponse très claire. Je prends souvent l’exemple du fabricant de tracteur John Deere, qui a pu parfois être défini comme « Tractor as a service », ce qui classerait un fabricant de tracteurs dans le numérique. Et par contre, Amazon qui a d’énormes entrepôts et beaucoup de main d’œuvre, qui pourrait tomber dans le champ non numérique. Donc il faut se méfier de ces problèmes de définition, qui finalement ont comme effets malencontreux d’handicaper un antitrust plus rapide, puisque c’est l’ambition notamment de ces outils. So, I'm turning now to Andreas with the same very straightforward question, so should the NCT be exclusively targeted towards digital markets? Andreas? Andreas Mundt: I echo to a certain extent what Isabelle has just said. A key question when it comes to these new instruments is, do we design them specifically for the digital area only or do we make them universally applicable since market failure is always possible also outside digital markets. I think we will have to be very pragmatic here. It is true that the problems we want to solve mainly relate to digital markets. They are the reason why we are thinking about enlarging our competition toolbox and they are the ones causing the biggest problems. From this point of view, it would make sense to limit these new tools to the digital economy. However, this approach clearly has its disadvantages. Who wants to distinguish a digital market from a non-digital market in the future? I assume that all markets we look at, including John Deere, the tractor producer mentioned by Nicolas, will become digital to a certain extent. And again, who wants to make that difference in the future? The second point is, if in the future it is no longer possible to make that difference, but you have identified structural competition problems on a market, do you really want to go to court and have a long debate whether something is digital or whether the focus is digital? I think we do not want to do that. With everyone calling for efficiency, there are good arguments supporting the introduction of a universally applicable tool. We had to deal with this question in Germany as well and we have, of course, encountered the same problems with regard to the 10th Amendment, just to conclude that. It might be an idea for the future to say that each company that is subject to these new tools must at least be active on digital markets. And this is the direction in which the Amendment is heading here in Germany by referring to another section in the existing law which relates to factors of market power with particular relevance for multi-sided markets and networks. So that could be a compromise, but I think everything else makes matters too complex and too many legal questions might be associated with this if we really limit the approach/instruments/tools to digital markets. Thank you. Nicolas Petit: Thank you, Andreas. Simeon, a quick reaction to that? Webinar #3 Digital: What regulatory model for platforms? Concurrences 11th New Frontiers of Antitrust - 5 November 2020 Verbatim transcript of oral presentations provided by Concurrences without prior vetting by the speakers. The views and opinions expressed in this Document do not necessarily represent those of the speakers’ institution or clients.
Simeon Thornton: Well, I think you're going to have quite a consensus on the panel because my short answer is no, I don't think the tool should be exclusively focused on digital markets. If you allow me a slightly longer answer, I think it's fairly clear that the NCT tool is based on the regime for market investigations that we established in 2002 in the UK. These are holistic investigations of whether a market is working well or not. And if it's not, they have strong order-making powers to address concerns that are harming consumers. We've had about 20 such market investigations since 2002. And if memory serves, precisely none of those have been focused predominantly on digital markets. Indeed, when you look at the sectors that have been the focus of those market investigations, including one I led recently on the energy market, it focused on utility sectors, so energy and retail banking, transport, airports, buses, etc, a lot on financial services and a whole range of quite heterogeneous markets, such as private hospitals and funerals. I am personally quite a champion of this tool. I think it is a powerful instrument that has allowed us at the CMA to effect real change in a number of important sectors of the economy. We've come up with quite innovative interventions from open banking, which came out of the retail banking market investigation, controls and outcomes where appropriate, that came out of the energy market investigation, a price cap, and divestiture in the case of BAA Airports. In answer to your question, I think this is an important tool for the CMA and would be an important tool for any competition authority, because it allows you to answer an exam question, which is quite different actually from the typical antitrust exam question, which is, has there been a transgression of the law that warrants a sanction? The exam questions that the market investigation I think the NCT would answer is, is there a problem in the market that warrants an intervention to improve outcomes for consumers? And it seems to me drawing on our experience of market investigations, that that question's equally relevant to non-digital, as well as digital markets. Nicolas Petit: Thank you. Thank you, Simeon. To bring maybe a sense of perspective here, when I was a baby antitrust student, I remember Philip Lowe, former Director-General at DG COMP, one his crusades when he was there was that competition policy had to move beyond simply talking about antitrust infringements and competition infringements, but he also wanted to get tools to deal with competition problems. Simeon Thornton: Yes. Nicolas Petit: Webinar #3 Digital: What regulatory model for platforms? Concurrences 11th New Frontiers of Antitrust - 5 November 2020 Verbatim transcript of oral presentations provided by Concurrences without prior vetting by the speakers. The views and opinions expressed in this Document do not necessarily represent those of the speakers’ institution or clients.
Vous pouvez aussi lire